Tiempo, conocimiento y dinámicas evolutivas: por qué las conexiones tienen importancia
Palabras clave:
Variedad dinámica, Organizaciones, Conocimiento, Instituciones, EvoluciónResumen
El tiempo tiene importancia porque el conocimiento se transforma. La incertidumbre knightiana excluye los procedimientos correctos y el conocimiento comprobado, pero da lugar a la imaginación y a la creatividad, las cuales impulsan el proceso evolutivo. La cognición humana depende menos de la lógica que de la elaboración de patrones; imponemos principios conectivos para establecer patrones y nexos causales entre ellos, como representaciones de fenómenos, las cuales son imperfectas y a menudo están supeditadas a múltiples interpretaciones. Los modelos estables fijan la línea de referencia para la selección. Nuestros modelos personales se complementan con continuidades institucionales; y organizaciones de diversos tipos ayudan a moldear el desarrollo del conocimiento, el cual prospera al establecer conexiones en los diversos márgenes del conocimiento existente.
Descargas
Citas
Barnard, C.I. (1938). The functions of the executive, Cambridge MA.: Harvard University Press.
Casson, M. (1982). The entrepreneur: an economic theory, Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Choi, Y.B. (1993). Paradigms and conventions: uncertainty, decision marking and entrepreneurship, EUA.: University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.
Coase, R.H. (1988). The firm, the market and the law, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal D. (1989). “Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D”, Economic Journal, 99: 569-596.
Dopfer, K. (2001). Frontiers of evolutionary economics: competition, self-organization and innovation policy, in Foster, J. Metcalfe, J.S. (eds) Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham Northampton, MA. Hahn, F.H. ([1973] 1984). “On the notion of equilibrium in economics”, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge Reprinted in Equilibrium and macroeconomics, pp. 43-71, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Hart, O.D. (1996). Firms, contracts and financial structure, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hicks, J.R. (1948). Value and capital, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
__________ (1982). Money, interest and wages: collected essays in economic theory, vol. 2, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
__________ (1976) (1982b). “Time in economics” in, Hicks (1982), pp. 282-300.
Hume, D. (1739-401 1978), in Selby-Bigge L, Nidditch PH (eds), A Treatise of human nature, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Kelly, G.A. (1963). A theory of personality, New York: Norton.
Kirzner, I.M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Knight, F.H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Lane, D., Malerba F., Maxfield R., Orsenigo, L. (1996). “Choice and action” in Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6(1), pp. 43-76.
Leijonhufvud, A. (2000). Macroeconomic instability and co-ordination, selected essays of Axel Leijonhufvud, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham Northampton, MA.
Loasby, B.J. (1976). Choice, complexity and ignorance: an enquiry into economic theory and the practice of decision making, Cambridge: Cambridge university Press.
__________ (1998). “Co-ordination failure in economic theory: economists in the 1930s” in Jolink A., Fontaine P. (eds), Historical perspectives on macroeconomics: 60 years after the general theory, pp 72-87, London: Routledge.
__________ (199). Knowledge, institutions and evolution in economics, London: Routledge.
__________ (2000). “Market institutions and economic evolution” en Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10, pp. 297-309.
__________ (2002). “Content and method: an epistemic perspective on some historical episodes” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 9(1).
Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics, London: Macmillan.
__________ (1994). Ye machine. Research in the history of economic thought and methodology, Greenwich, C.T. : Archival Suppl 4, 116-132. JAI press.
Ménard, C. (1995). “Markets as institutions versus organizations as markets? Disentangling some fundamental concepts” en Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28, pp. 161-182.
Menger, C. (1976). Principles of economics; translated by, Dingwall, J., Hoselitz, B.F., New New York :York University Press, 1871.
Metcalfe, J.S. (2000). “Evolutionary approaches to population thinking and the problem of growth and development” in Dopfer, K. (ed), Evolutionary economics: program and scope, London: Boston Dordrecht, pp. 14-164, Kluwer.
Myerson, R.B. (1999). “Nash equilibrium and the history of economic theory” in Journal of Economic Literature, 37, pp. 1067-1082.
Nightingale, P. (2000). “Economies of scale in experimentation: knowledge and technology in pharmaceutical, R&D”, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, pp. 315-359.
Nooteboom, B. (1992). “Towards a dynamic theory of transactions” in Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 2, pp. 281-299.
Penrose, E.T. (1952). “Biological analogies in the theory of the firm” in American Economic Review, 42, pp. 804-819.
__________ (1959, 1995). The theory of the wroth of the firm, Basil Blackwell, Oxford (1959); 3rd edn: Oxford University Press, Oxford (1995).
Popper K.R. (1963). Conjectures and refutations, Routledge and Kegan, Paul, London.
Potts, J. (2000). The new evolutionary microeconomics, complexity, competence and adaptive behaviour, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Richardson, G.B. (1953). Imperfect knowledge and economic efficiency, Oxford Economic Papers 5(2), pp. 116-156, reprinted in: Richardson, G.B. (1998), pp.1-21.
__________ (1959). “Equilibrium, expectations and information” in Economic Journal, 69, pp. 223-237, reprinted in Richardson, G.B. (1998), pp. 51-65.
Descargas
Publicado
Cómo citar
Número
Sección
Licencia
Esta obra está bajo una licencia internacional Creative Commons Atribución-NoComercial-SinDerivadas 4.0.